Obtain the data you need to make the most informed decisions by accessing our extensive portfolio of information, analytics, and expertise. Sign in to the product or service center of your choice.
What was initially expected to be a transitory period of
moderately higher consumer price inflation across the globe has
morphed into a phase of persistent, exceptionally high inflation
rates, captured in the evolution of annual forecasts for 2022.
Upward pressures stemming initially from a range of primarily
coronavirus disease 2019 (COVID-19)-related effects are now being
aggravated by various spillover effects following Russia's invasion
of Ukraine. Focusing on Europe, we assess various arguments for and
against such a shift.
What was viewed initially by central banks as a transitory
pick-up in inflation has turned into something much more
worrisome.
Eurozone inflation is likely to be persistently higher in
future than during the pre-pandemic years.
This reflects a range of influences, some global and some
local.
A scenario of unmoored inflation expectations and wage-price
spirals is less probable, though the risks need close monitoring,
particularly in other parts of Europe.
The case for
Various factors suggest that inflation rates will be higher in
future than those we became used to in the decades prior to the
COVID-19 pandemic. These include:
Waning effects of global disinflationary forces.
Over-stimulative policy and constraints on tightening.
Rising inflation expectations.
Climate change and energy transition.
Waning global forces
A confluence of factors contributed to sustained disinflationary
forces across the global economy from the late 1980s and early
1990s. These included the decline of communism in eastern Europe,
the EU's expansion and abolition of trade barriers, and China's
accession to the World Trade Organization (WTO). Accompanied by
exceptional increases in global investment and trade, facilitated
in part by major advances in supply chain management and shipping,
the result was a huge increase in the pool of global labour and
sustained low costs of production.
While extreme events such as the COVID-19 pandemic and Russia's
invasion of Ukraine have been fundamental to the short-term surge
in goods inflation rates, they are also likely to reinforce the
longer-term trend away from many of the disinflationary forces
which held it down in the past. Global trade as a share of GDP
peaked back in 2008 and more recently, the "trade wars" from 2018
and the subsequent extreme disruptions caused by the pandemic and
the Russia-Ukraine conflict suggest security of supply chains is
likely to take priority over competitive pricing for key products.
The attraction of outsourcing is also diminishing for various
reasons.
Expectations and policy
If a central bank is credible in its commitment to maintaining
price stability, longer-term inflation expectations should remain
well anchored, preventing wage and price-setting behaviour being
subject to inflationary fears.
However, there have been signs recently that inflation
expectations might be becoming less well anchored and there may be
constraints (e.g., political pressures, recession risks, declining
asset prices) on how far central banks are willing to go to keep
them in check.
While the recent pick-up has been most apparent in shorter-term,
consumer-based measures of inflation expectations, this is still
relevant as they can influence wage bargaining. While the signals
from longer-term inflation expectations have been more comforting,
there too some warning signs are flashing. Although surveys of
forecasters' expectations appear well anchored still, they
typically do not deviate far from central bank inflation targets.
In contrast, market-derived measures have picked up markedly since
2020 in some cases, though the trends are not uniform.
The differences in policy responses and economic recoveries
following the GFC and COVID-19 pandemic are striking. The
unprecedented magnitude of the contractions in activity during the
initial phase of the latter in spring 2020, and the fiscal space
provided by the exceptionally rapid and substantial QE by major
central banks - including the ECB - led to very different fiscal
responses and economic outcomes. Initial fears of another Great
Depression, leaving permanent scars, proved to be way too
pessimistic.
The recession was exceptionally deep but also unusually short.
When the COVID-19-related constraints eased, output rebounded
unusually rapidly. Since the rebound, policy has remained
exceptionally stimulatory, including fiscally, supporting demand
during a period when supply has responded unusually slowly due to
various impediments.
Climate change
The various channels through which climate change could generate
higher future inflation rates include:
Global warming is associated with a greater incidence of
damaging climatic events which may impact specific prices, notably
for food.
The transition to a net zero carbon emission world implies
sharp increases in the price of carbon, in turn affecting consumer
prices directly through higher energy prices, and indirectly
through increased costs of production.
Higher prices for the commodities essential to the deployment
of "green technologies".
The case against
The counter arguments against a regime change for inflation
include:
Rebalancing of supply and demand.
Regime changes require multiple shocks.
Technological factors, including e-commerce and
automation.
Labour market reforms and competitiveness challenges.
Rebalancing
Unlike in the aftermath of the GFC, supply has been unusually
unresponsive to higher demand during the recovery from the COVID-19
pandemic, aggravated recently by the Russia-Ukraine conflict. This
is apparent in various indicators, including extremely long
suppliers' delivery times (evident in our PMI data), soaring
transport costs, including for shipping, and shortages of key
inputs to production.
Over time, some of these supply problems will ease. Either
because supply adapts, the constraints due to the pandemic and the
Russia-Ukraine conflict diminish, or demand weakens. Regarding the
latter, household real incomes will be hit exceptionally hard in
2022 by soaring inflation, with the deterioration in household
purchasing power potentially leading to lower underlying
inflation.
Multiple shocks required
Looking back at historical experiences, once a low-inflation
regime has become well established, a switch to a high-inflation
regime generally requires a combination of shocks to occur. In the
eurozone specifically, it would be difficult to argue against a
low-inflation regime having been well established prior to the
COVID-19 pandemic.
The caveat with this argument, however, is that the type of
shocks historically required for a shift into a higher-inflation
regime are precisely those which we are experiencing now, including
excessively expansionary monetary and fiscal policies, as
highlighted above.
Technological factors, including e-commerce and
automation
The rise in digital technology and e-commerce has not only
lowered costs but also kept a lid on inflation by allowing
consumers to comparison shop, with the resulting price transparency
increasing competition and curtailing businesses' pricing
power.
Technological advances which enable machines to perform a wider
range of tasks also hold down production costs. The use of
artificial intelligence (AI) is still in its relatively early
stages and is yet to spread to most of the economy, reflected in
the relatively low use of robots compared to the numbers of people
employed.
Labor market reforms and internal
devaluations
One notable feature of the low-flation environment in the
eurozone from the mid-2000s was member states copying many aspects
of the labour reforms introduced in Germany. In short, pursuing
wage moderation in order to improve competitiveness, preserving
employment.
With the option of nominal exchange rate devaluations no longer
available to eurozone member states, competitiveness improvements
have to be achieved the hard way, via "internal" devaluations:
i.e., through adjustments in relative unit labour costs, either via
higher productivity or more commonly, though wage moderation.
The picture is not uniform across Europe, however. The UK in
particular looks vulnerable to "second round" effects on inflation
given persistently higher inflation expectations and reduced labor
supply, related to Brexit, along with parts of emerging Europe,
though the huge inflows of migrants from Ukraine could help to
alleviate the risks from labor shortages in the latter.
Bottom line
There are persuasive arguments for and against a shift to a new
regime of persistently higher inflation rates in Europe. We need to
distinguish, however, between a new regime where inflation is
higher than in the pre-pandemic period but remains around the
central bank's target rate and one in which inflation expectations
become unmoored and a wage-price spiral could follow.
In the eurozone, we believe the former is the more likely,
reflected in our forecasts. The risk of the second outcome looks
comparatively low in the eurozone for various reasons, including
the long period of persistently low inflation prior to the COVID-19
shock. Still, we need to monitor the risks closely, particularly in
countries where the potential for wage-price spirals looks more
worrisome.
Posted 18 May 2022 by Ken Wattret, Vice President, Economics, S&P Global Market Intelligence
This article was published by S&P Global Market Intelligence and not by S&P Global Ratings, which is a separately managed division of S&P Global.